FEATURE STORY

Managing Food Price Volatility

February 2, 2015


STORY HIGHLIGHTS
  • When food prices spike, net food buyers in poor countries suffer, with urban households the hardest hit. Over the long-term, however, rising food prices result in higher wages and lower poverty.
  • While price insulation is a rational response for individual countries, collectively it exacerbates price shocks and appears to be ineffective in protecting the poor.
  • Governments should consider tools such as social safety nets, stockpiling, and market-based risk mitigation to help the poor deal with food price shocks.

When the prices of food staples surge, the food security of people around the world can be threatened in a matter of days. In 2007 and 2008, spikes in food prices pushed approximately 100 million people into poverty, according to Research Manager Will Martin’s analysis. However, it is important for policy makers to understand that the short-run impact of food prices on vulnerable populations does not present a complete picture of their long-term effect on poverty levels around the world.

Will Martin delivered this month’s Policy Research Talk, which focused on the topic of “Food Price Changes, Price Insulation, and Poverty.” The Policy Research Talks are a monthly event held by the research department to foster a dialogue between researchers and their colleagues across the World Bank. The topic of mitigating threats to food security is an important aspect of risk management and volatility.

Research Director Asli Demirguc-Kunt highlighted the complex policy implications of an increasingly integrated international economy in the context of the Bank’s twin goals to end extreme poverty by 2030 and boost shared prosperity. “Trade integration is an important catalyst of development, but it generates unequal gains. How should its distributional impact be managed?” she asked.

With co-authors Kym Anderson and Maros Ivanic, Martin’s research shows that in the short-run, the effect of price increases on welfare depends on whether households are net buyers or net sellers. Urban households are negatively affected, as are many farm households in poor countries, which are often net buyers as well; food price changes affect the cost of living and the value of output from the household business. In the long-term, increases in food prices lower poverty rates: Martin’s analysis indicates that it takes two to three years for price increases to translate into wage increases, but that the resulting increases in real wages for unskilled workers can be substantial. Ultimately, the effects are unequal, with rural households generally benefitting more than urban, which remain worse off after food price increases.

In his talk, Martin explored the political imperatives that drive agricultural trade policy. According to political economy theory, policy makers set the level of trade protection based on the strength of political support and the cost of protecting particular sectors. This protection tends to result in high average protection in rich importers and low protection in poor exporters. However, “the past few years of price volatility reveal something different: policy makers set domestic prices to insulate their countries against sudden price shocks, particularly for staples, but in the longer-term they pass through the changes in prices,” said Martin. Drawing on consumer price index data from developing countries compared to world prices, Martin demonstrated that while governments lowered import duties or imposed export barriers to provide strong insulation for rice and wheat prices—two politically sensitive food items—over the long-run, domestic and international prices converge.


Image

" Collectively, insulation appears to be ineffective. We need to develop policies that work. "

Will Martin

Research Manager


While the decision to impose measures against increases in world prices is a rational one for any individual country, their widespread use creates collective action problems, with each country’s attempt to lower its own domestic price contributing to very large increases in world prices—a situation that Martin compared to a stadium full of people, all simultaneously standing to get a better view. In 2006-2008, it appears that almost half the increase in world prices for rice arose from countries’ attempts to hold down their own domestic prices.

Anabel Gonzalez, Senior Director of the World Bank Group Trade and Competitiveness Global Practice, called a collective solution optimal, but warned that “agricultural trade policy is distorted and politically charged.” Gonzalez discussed the importance of concluding the Doha Round, calling for countries to commit to not adopting export restrictions; highlighted the value of trade facilitation and transport services liberalization; and pointed to the opportunities created by Trade for Aid. Developing countries could also benefit from stronger social safety nets, stockpiling, diversification of food baskets, and private-sector risk management mechanisms like crop insurance, but Gonzalez acknowledged some of these may be challenging to implement.  


Api
Api

Welcome